Anarchy 83/Tenants take over
Tenants take over
a new strategy for
council tenants
The facts and opinions presented here are intended as ammunition
By 1965 they had become[3]
The figures differ according to whether a dwelling or a household is being counted and according to the definitions used, and they are also different for various parts of Britain. For example, the figures for England only in 1964, counting households, wereCite error: Invalid <ref>
tag;
invalid names, e.g. too many
while another estimate, in terms of dwellings,[4] gives
The proportions of council-owned dwellings varies greatly. “The Newcastle Corporation controls two out of every five of the city’s houses. In Greenock, on the West Coast of Scotland, half the population live in council houses.”[4] The London Borough of Kensington has 5% council tenants, while Dagenham has 67%.[5]
The general trend is clear, and, since it concerns a commodity so basic, durable and socially important as housing, it is one of the dramatic social changes of this century. Private renting, which before the First World War accounted for over 90% of households, is declining rapidly for reasons which are well known. Just as rapidly owner-occupation and renting from local authorities is increasing. The proportionate increase of these two tenure groups depends of course, on government policy, as well as on opportunity and increasing affluence. The post-war Labour government, through building licensing and a quota system, put the emphasis on building by local authorities. The
When building societies first came into existence as organs of working-class mutual aid at the end of the 18th century, they were remarkably like the self-build housing societies of today, and very unlike the money-lending-pus-savings-bank organisations which are the modern building societies. They consisted of groups of people who saved to buy land to house themselves, and when the first house was completed, borrowed money on its security to build another, until all the members of the society were housed, at which point the society disbanded. In a sense they resembled the method of financing house purchase used by some groups of immigrants in this country today:
The building societies changed their character in the nineteenth century to become more permanent societies, separating the people whoParticularly among Indians and Pakistanis, housing finance pools are found with a substantial membership—perhaps as many as 900—which meet periodically once a fortnight or once a month, and make calls of, say £10 on each member. Those who draw upon the fund thus created are subject thereafter to periodic calls until the whole amount drawn by them has been liquidated. Drawings under this system are substantial and may cover the whole purchase cost. Occasionally, West Indians operate on similar but less ambitious lines. … Their pooling arrangements usually only provide for the initial deposits necessary for house purchase, thus enabling them to “get off the ground”.[5]
The housing society movement since then has never lost this “charitable” emphasis, and in this respect is in marked contrast to the co-operative housing associations of several other countries. Mr. Lewis Waddilove contrasts the situation here with that in Sweden, where the movement
depended strongly on the initiative of tenants it did not, as in the United Kingdom, become the instrument of liberal employers and philanthropists making provision for what were referred to as the “working classes”. The tenants’s unions of Sweden discovered that the best way of preventing the making of undue profits from a housing shortage and to raise housing standards was to build and administer their own hoes. As an example, in 1923, the tenants’ union of Stockholm became The Tenants’ Savings and Building Society and in the following year similar movements in other towns came together to form a National Association of Housing Societies known throughout Sweden by the initials HSB. … A second national body for housing associations has been formed by the trade unions in Sweden concerned with the building industry. HSB remains the largest national body and its very name measures out the difference between the Swedish and the British housing association movement. In Sweden the movement’s inspiration and drive come from the tenants; they save for the purpose of raising their own housing standards.
In Britain the initiative in the movement has come from philanthropists and others concerned to raise the housing standards of the “working class”. Save in the “self-build” societies, the initiative rests with the occupants of the houses who are simply the tenants of the association.[1]
He describes how the HSB has built up not only resources of expert advice in building, planning and finance, “but has become a centre of research, the results of which can immediately be applied in its own large-scale activities. This means that the tiniest housing co-operative in a remote township” has access to the best of advice, architectural and technical, with the result that “the standard of design, workmanship and finish are well in advance of comparable dwellings in this country. … So competent is the research, technical and even manufacturing organisation of HSB that municipalities have been glad to avail themselves of it. Many local authorities’ housing schemes are in fact planned and executed by HSB; in some areas municipal houses are built and managed by a ‘municipal company’ on the directorate of which the local authority and HSB are represented”.[1]
In Britain, at least until the initiation in 1966 of the Co-ownership Development Society, the nearest thing we have had to HSB has beenAll the political parties express their support for the housing society idea, and it was amid general approval that the Housing Act of 1961 (in Section 7) made available £25 million for direct government loans at the then current rate of interest, to be administered through the National Federation to housing societies building new dwellings to be kept available for cost-rent letting, without subsidy. The Minister described his £25 million as a “pump-priming” operation, meaning that he wanted to encourage private capital to go the same way. This of course was the same pious hope that was expressed by the philanthropists a hundred years ago, and it met with the same lack of success.
Then in 1964, the government set up the Housing Corporation with Admiral Sir Caspar John as its head, and offices in Park Lane, with power to dispense another £100 million in loans to housing societies for both cost-rent and co-ownership schemes.
The results of both these attempts to stimulate the growth of housing societies has been disappointing.
The Corporation’s last report showed that by the end of September 1966, 150 cost-rent projects, involving 6,932 dwellings and costing about £26.7 millions, had been approved together with a further 42 co-ownership schemes, had been registered with the corporation.[6] Commencing on the implications of the report, which declared that a large potential market exists for co-ownership housing, Sir Caspar John admitted that co-ownership housing had developed slowly, adding hopefully that “things have speeded up tremendously in the past six months”.[7]
I have referred to the rate of expansion of the housing society movement as disappointing, but perhaps the surprising thing is that it expanded at all, as so many legal and fiscal obstacles stood in its way. In the first place the original cost-rent scheme could only benefit people with an income (five years ago) above about £1,500 a year, while such people, because of the system of taxation and tax allowances would have found freehold house purchase a better proposition. Secondly, and partly because of the difficulty of finding a legal framework—even after 100 years of the Co-operative Movement—for the concept of co-ownership, the whole system was so complex that only groups containing someone with specialist knowledge were likely even to under
The 1961 Co-operative Party policy statement reiterated the point that “very little change of policy would be necessary to give practical encouragement to the formation of co-operative housing societies”[10] and
The Committee’s report went on: “To think of the tenants of today as though their circumstances and needs are the same as those of tenants of a generation ago would be unreal. Similarly, to expect methods of management designed to meet the needs of tenants in the 1930s to be suitable for those of the 1950s or 1970s would, we think, be quite wrong. &hellip” But what of the tenants of the 1960s? Has there been a change in the attitudes of housing management? It would be difficult to find evidence for this.
The time is ripe for change. But change of what kind? I believeThe visitor to housing estates on the Continent comments most often on the attractiveness of their layout, the care with which common land is cultivated, and the harmony of external decoration. The claim of the co-operative association is that it combines the sense of ownership and the security of tenure of the owner-occupied house with an equally strong sense of responsibility for, and interest in, the neighbourhood as a whole. Moreover it does this as a by-product of its normal organisation; in Britain in new estates we have attempted to achieve the same result by all kinds of artificial stimuli to neighbourhood responsibility.
The sense of responsibility comes from being responsible, and people can only be responsible for their own lives and their own environment if they are in control of it. Similarly Professor Donnison declares:[14]
… we need a system that will provide adequate housing of various types with complete security of tenure. Down payments should be negligible but subsequent payments may well be higher than council rents. The occupier should be given responsibility and incentives for maintaining and improving his own house, but should be insured against the costs of major repairs. Some body responsible to the occupiers themselves should retain a continuing interest in the character and development of the immediate neighbourhood and might provide open space and other shared amenities for its residents. In fact a way must be found to continue the advantages of owner-occupation and tenancy, both in new housing and in existing property.
The points which require emphasis in his conclusions are that the overall body should be responsible to the occupiers themselves and that it is not enough to develop this new kind of tenure for future application: it must be applied to existing property.
Mr. J. B. Cullingworth raises similar questions, in fact a whole series of them:[15]
Could not tenants be given a greater degree of responsibility for the upkeep of their houses and, probably more important, for the general appearance and amenities of housing estates? There is a growing discussion of the value of “citizen-participation” in urban renewal in the rehabilitation of “twilight areas”. Is not a similar line possible with council housing estates? Surely it is not only owner-occupiers who are hit by the “do-it-yourself revolution” and who have a real concern for their houses and the environment in which they live. More fundamentally, why do we need council housing? If it is a question of ensuring that low-income families can obtain good housing at a price which they can afford, could not this be achieved by a system of family housing allowances? If it is a question of ensuring that sufficient houses are actually built, could not local authorities simply confine their attention to housebuilding and hand over the completed houses to associations of tenants, housing co-operatives, housing societies, or even (with the aid of generous mortgage facilities) to individual families? A “reserve” of houses could be kept for special needs, but it need not be on the vast scale of today.
Yet the generalisations are made. “Property owners,” says Ferdynand Zweig,[16] “often struck me as a brighter, more daring and enterprising breed than the rest. … I often assked how people felt when they became house-owners. … The overwhelming majority felt deeply about it,” and the words which came to their lips were satisfaction, self-confidence, freedom, independence. And James Tucker, describing the effects of segregation by house tenure and the frightening animosities which exist between owner-occupiers and council tenants,[17] feels able to isolate certain characteristics of council tenants:
Now, what of the people? There are two dominant characteristics, one at least of which I cannot claim to be the first to have noticed. It is unneighbourliness, often resulting in loneliness; the other seems to be based on an acceptance of the notion that people in council houses have failed, haven’t quite made it, and is frequently expressed as a frustrated desire to buy a house off the estate.
Many council tenants speak with gentle pride of how little they have to do with people living near them. … In some measure it may be a means of self-protection against neighbours not considered up to the social mark. But, more important, it is a defensive assertion against the low social standing of estates: “Look! We can be as unfriendly as anybody.” People ape what they assume to be superior ways of behaving; suburban ways, for instance. It is tragic that it should be so and leads to great unhappiness. …
In so far as we may consider the generalisations to be valid, we can see that they arise from the social situations in which people find themselves. The walls or fences which in a number of notorious instances have been built to separate privately-owned from council-owned sections of the same estate are an extreme manifestation of ordinary English snobbery, but they make it devastatingly clear to the more vulnerable kind of municipal tenant that in they eyes of millions of his fellow-countrymen he is a second-class citizen. The way in which his relationship with his landlord intensifies this feeling has been made clear by Stanley Alderson:[18]
… the usual balance of power between landlord and tenant is everywhere upset by the condition of housing shortage. But the problems10are much more acute in council tenancy. It is not only that the council tenant is even less free to move than the private tenant. The private tenant can at least hate his landlord for taking advantage of the conditions of shortage for his own financial gain. The council tenant knows that he is fortunate in having his house, and feels that he has been done a favour. The local authority which is his landlord never does anything for its own financial gain. It always acts in its wisdom for its tenants’ own advantage. In the long run, power employed paternalistically provokes far greater resentment than power employed selfishly or even antagonistically. Because there is no satisfactory outlet for it, the resentment accumulates. …
Worse still, every attempt to rationalise rent policy serves to exacerbate this paternalistic relationship, for Mr. Alderson goes on:
We need to find a system of tenure which changes this psychology of dependency for one of independence. One which, as Harold Campbell puts it, “combines private enterprise and mutual aid in a unique form of social ownership which puts a premium on personal responsibility and individual initiative”.[9]It is often said of industrial strikes over wages that their real cause is repressed resentment deriving from day-to-day industrial relationships. Similarly the rent strikes that followed the introduction of differential rent schemes must have given release to repressed resentment deriving from landlord-tenant relations. The protests against a means test were not merely rationalisations of a reluctance to pay higher rents. Differential rents were resented because they foisted on the local authorities the ultimate paternalist responsibility of deciding how much pocket money their tenants should be allowed to keep. Local authorities deserve sympathy for their reluctance to exercise this responsibility. It is an imperative that they should be relieved of it as that council tenants who can afford to should pay economic rents. The council tenant who needs financial assistance should receive it through some other organ of the state, established to assist private tenants and owner-occupiers as well. He could then claim his assistance without loss of dignity, and he would always pay his full rent to his landlord. Equally his landlord would always be entitled to claim it from him.
In the first phase, the association played mainly a representative role, negotiating with the local authority for essential services and organising large-scale socials and protest meetings. In the second it became mainly a constructive organisation, fully occupied in building a community centre. In the third phase the centre’s finances were placed on a firm foundation; and in the fourth, popular wishes were discovered through a process of trial and error. In the fifth period, short-run equilibrium was reached: the activities of the centre followed a routine pattern. This was the path of evolution of the ost successful centre studies; the others failed to make such rapid adjustments, and lost most of their membership.[20]
Testifying to the value of such associations, the Central Housing Advisory Committee reported that, “The attitude of local authorities towards tenants’ associations tends to vary according to the circumstances in which an association has sprung up. Naturally the main purpose of most associations is to watch over the interests of the tenant. Their approach may differ widely, some starting with the belief that the interests of the tenant and landlord are inevitably opposed. We believe, however, that whatever the starting point, the wise course for the local authority is to treat associations as responsible bodies and seek to secure their confidence and co-operation …”[13] (the Committee’s italics).
Describing the activities of the associations, Mr. Hayes notes that, “Their objects are usually threefold; to encourage good neighbourliness; and to provide facilities for recreational activities; and to work for the benefit of the residents generally. Usually their method is to organise social activities first, and later to serve as a consultative committee for the estate, acting as a link with housing management for the discussion of common problems of living on the estate. The advantage of having such a representative group to consult as a ‘consumer council’ has only slowly been recognised by housing managers.”[21]
Since, I am in fact, advocating that tenants’ associations should evolve from this consultative status to that of actual control, I should perhaps cite a contradictory opinion. Messrs. Morris and Mogey, in The Sociology of Housing observe that,
Councils are apt to be cautious in granting self-government to their tenants, and this is to some extent justified by the tenants’ diversity and inexperience. Others feel that paternal watchfulness and control by the local authority can easily outgrow the bounds of reason; and give only the minimum of tenancy conditions and unsought advice. This represents the other extreme from paternalism: it assumes such a strong relationship that tenants will feel free to make any requests to the local authority. It12gives tenants’ associations much more responsibility than they are structured to carry. They lack the power to discipline their own members, and cannot therefore bargain successfully or act firmly on their members’ behalf. To find a balance between paternalism and laissez-faire requires skill; for tenants’ associations will tend to be effectively suppressed if either extreme policy is adopted.[23]
But has anyone ever tried giving real responsibilities to tenants’ associations? Apart from the handful of examples of co-operative co-partnership housing associations, there is very little evidence to draw upon. This is certainly a lesson to learn from one particular field of private enterprise housing. The general standard of design in speculative house-building is abysmally low, but the outstanding exceptions in post-war private development have been in the work of Span Developments Ltd. and Wates Ltd. Wates arrange for the shared facilities of their estates to be the responsibility of a management company composed of the residents themselves, which, they claim, “also allows people to get to know and help each other (in matters like babysitting for example) without intruding into each other’s essential privacy”. And in the Span developments there has been developed a method of residents’ control, described by the architect Eric Lyons as a “special technique of leasehold purchase, which is effecting a quiet revolution in property ownership” and he claims for the system that
… It has solved the old problem of maintenance of common spaces and structures, and also involves each resident in the autonomous Residents’ Society which runs each estate. … The scheme which has a Residents’ Society very carefully formed on a non-profit-making basis under the Friendly Societies Acts … is a method of guaranteeing the permanent maintenance of the building, and not only the building fabric, but the gardens and general amenities. It is also of singular benefit in involving each individual in the idea, each person who lives there. That seems to be socially a tremendous thing.
… As far as I am concerned, it does not affect me whether it is leasehold or not. The important thing is that the Residents’ Societies are in charge legally and formally. They have their own committees and take an active part. If someone’s child starts digging up the lawn, someone will want to know why. Everyone has a stake in the issue. …[24]
His last sentence explains why it is reasonable to expect that genuine control by tenants’ co-operatives would be successful. To suggest that the middle-class residents of Span estates have some quality which is lacking in council house tenants, apart from larger incomes, is to deny the whole edifice of mutual aid organisation which the working class has built up in the past. (In fact, a resident of one Span development at Blackheath remarked that “We have all the advantages without the disadvantages of a working class district. The estate has achieved a high degree of neighbourliness.”[25])
And if it is really true that tenant control would give tenants’ associations more responsibility than they are “structured to carry”, or that the tenants’ diversity and inexperience would make it impossible, how are we to explain the success of the extreme case which Mr. Waddilove reports from Norway?
A pre-war municipal estate near Oslo was transferred over a period from the ownership of the local authority to the ownership of associations13of the tenants themselves. It has been one of the most difficult problems to the local authority; its standards were low, its appearance unpleasant, and there was great resistance to increases in rents to a reasonable level. A series of meetings patiently arranged by the housing manager ultimately resulted in the acceptance by the tenants of membership in co-operatives which, on favourable terms, took over the ownership of the property from the local authority. Today it is transformed. The members have cared for their own property and by corporate action have ensured that others have done so in a way that they failed to do when it was in public ownership; proposed by the municipality at which they protested so vigorously. The experience so impressed the authority that it decided in principle to transfer all its post-war estates similarly to the ownership of tenant co-operatives and to base its housing policy on this principle.[1]
What proportion of council tenants would like to buy the houses they occupy, and are financially able to do so? It is hard to make an estimate. Several years ago Ferdynand Zweig observed that “The tendency to consider house property as something worth having and struggling for, something which gives one strength and self-confidence and social standing, appears to be spreading among the working classes. I have no figures to offer here but I think that the working classes may be divided into three main groups, numerically not very far apart. One group tries to acquire property; the second does not think about house roperty at all,, as it is beyond its possibilities and its ken; the third group rejects the acquisition of house property outright as undesirable and even pernicious for the working man”.[16] On the other hand, James Tucker noted in 1966 that
Commenting on the actual response of tenants in Birmingham and Reading to offers from the council of the chance to buy their houses, Brian Lapping (The Guardian, 15.5.67) says, “What is surprising is how few people in council houses have taken the chance to buy them. Reading’s 1,500 have taken five years. In Birmingham so far only 2½% of those offered the chance have bought. Nobody knows why the response rate has been low. Perhaps it is because of the freeze, perhaps because most council tenants don’t like their homes enough to want toIt is unusual, though that is all, to come across council tenants who would not prefer to be owner-occupiers, possibly of council-built property, but more often of a house away from municipal estates. It would be wild to suggest that all those who want to go are seeking an escape from council housing because its social rating is low. More simply, property appreciates and many council tenants feel they are missing something: their objections are not to renting council property but to renting. Yet it is worth noticing that a lot of council tenants regard those who have moved off to their own houses as having taken a leap upward in social standing. The other side of that thought can only be shame or frustration or aggressiveness at finding themselves left behind.[17]
As with most issues connected with housing, opinions on the sale of council housing have polarised on political lines. This applies even to opinions on the success or failure of the campaign to sell the. Thus at the Scarborough Conference of the Labour Party, Mr. Greenwood, Minister of Housing, defending his policy of disagreeing but not intervening, declared that “The rate of sale is falling: it is lower today than a year ago” (Guardian, 3.10.67), while on the other hand Mr. Horace Cutler, the new Conservative chairman of the Greater London Council’s Housing Committee, claims that “There has been a fantastic response to the GLC’s ‘buy your own home’ scheme for council tenants”. Both in Birmingham and London, the Councils do not propose to offer to tenants more than 10% of their houses. The rate of response in London is certainly higher than in Birmingham, probably about 10% of tenants to whom the offer has been made have started negotiating. If we assume that the same figure would apply to the 90% of tenants who have not been offered the chance, this would mean that about one in a hundred to council tenants feels able or anxious to buy his house. When you look at it in this light, it is hard to see what the fuss is about.
The arguments which have been used by the Labour Party in opposition to the sale of council houses have hardly been of a kind to convince the uncommitted. It is suggested that the sale of houses to tenants would have the effect of depriving people waiting on the councils’ lists, but in fact these houses would be occupied as tenants by the would-be purchasers in any case. (The actual number of occupied council dwellings which fall vacant in London is only 1½ to 2% a year.) It is extraordinary that in the public discussion of this issue, no one has made the point that transfer of ownership collectively to a tenants’ association is infinitely preferable to the selling of a small number of odd houses whose tenants happen to be ready and willing to buy them, one by one. This could be an alternative more attractive both to the tenant and to the council.
It would extend the benefits of independence much more widely.
- advice on the design and layout of estates from the management point of view;
- the study of housing needs in the borough or district;
- the selection of tenants;
- the allocation of accommodation;
- the fixing of rents and the levying of occupation charges;
- the collection of, and accounting for, rents, rates and other charges due from tenants;
- the upkeep, maintenance and repair of houses and estates, the adaptation, improvement and conversion of properties;
- the provision of caretaking services and the operation of special estate services (laundries, lifts, community centres, clubrooms, etc.);
- the enforcement of tenancy conditions, the maintenance of good order, the care of elderly, infirm, and unsatisfactory tenants.
If an estate were taken over by a tenant co-operative, the first two of these functions would not be its concern. (Though, of course, if the normal means of providing housing became by way of housing societies rather than by way of local authorities, they would become everybody’s concern.) We have therefore to consider how a co-operative might manage items 3 to 9.
Selection of Tenants: Local authorities vary enormously in their selection criteria. (See for example Jane Morton: “The Council House Raffle”, New Society, 23.11.67.) The one basic principle is that allocation and selection is based on need rather than merit. But the “weighting” of various kinds of need is bound to be arbitrary, and there is no reason to suppose that a committee of tenants, selecting a candidate to fill a vacancy, would have any less valid a conception of fairness than the housing department’s officials. However, some other criteria usually ignored in council selection may, quite legitimately be adopted. Morris and Mogey[23] note that with the usual selection methods “legitimate public or group interests may be largely ignored” and mention the findings of Young and Willmott on the break-up of the extended family through housing policy. “Experience in establishing co-operative comAllocation: Since we are considering existing estates where vacancies occur one by one, problems of allocation scarcely arise, and when they do, once again, there is no reason to suppose that the sense of fair play of a tenants’ co-operative is any less developed than that of the housing manager. The swapping of dwellings would probably be easier to arrange between members of a co-operative than through the bureaucracy of housing management.
Rents: Few people would deny that the whole field of payment for housing is in an absurd situation, and that if subsidies are to be made (including the concealed subsidy of tax concessions for owner-occupiers) it would be more equitable to subsidise families rather than subsidise particular dwellings. Readers will readily agree that social welfare is no substitute for social justice, but that until we can achieve the latter we have to utilise the former. I assume therefore that after a transfer from municipal to co-operative control, the co-operative would levy rent on its members in relation to its commitments and that subsidies for members would be obtained through the machinery of social welfare rather than through that of housing. We do not want the ability to pay an economic rent to be the criterion of membership of a housing co-operative, while at the same time we know that housing subsidies today do not reach those whose need for them is greatest.
Collection and Accountancy: A small co-operative might provide these services for itself, a large one might pay for them to be professionally provided.
Upkeep and Maintenance: This is likely to be a much less expensive proposition for a co-operative than for a council’s maintenance department. Mr. Campbell notes in his pamphlet that the members of housing co-operatives “have a keen interest in maintaining their homes in good repair and indeed, constantly to improve them”. The co-operative policy statement on Social Ownership[10] remarked that “We see no reason why many councils should not contract with small producer co-operatives for at least the maintenance of their properties.” Exactly the same thing applies to housing co-operatives.
Communal Services: A real community would probably provide these services on a voluntary rota basis. If in practice it was unable to do this, it could pay for them, utilising the services of its elderly or teenage members.
Good Order: Any housing manager will tell you of his impotence in the face of anti-social behaviour on estates. Good order comes from good community relationships which are far more likely under conditions of tenant responsibility than external responsibility.
Social Welfare: Opinions within the world of housing management differ greatly as to the extent to which social welfare is a housing responsibility. It is certain however that the members of a well-developed tenants’ association will see it as a community responsibility. “We are our own social workers,” explained a member of one of the
In London, under Section 23(3) of the London Government Act, 1963, the Minister has power by order, to provide for the transfer to a housing association of any housing accommodation belonging to the Greater London Council or the Council of a London borough provided, in the latter case, that it is outside the borough.
The financial arrangement for the take-over should probably be based on the experience of the existing co-operative housing societies. It might be for instance that the co-operative is advanced a mortgage by the council (the price agreed being based on the members’ status as sitting tenants) for the whole or a part of the purchase price, any other loan being arranged through the Co-ownership Development Society, and each member contributing to a share liability which might in the first instance be nominal.
Or, on the other hand, and if the arrangement is to be made more attractive to members than individual house ownership, some arrangement must be made for a tenant, on moving out, to receive his share of the appreciation of the property. Mrs. Wallis, who acted as arbitrator for a co-operative self-build housing society told the National Federation how this was done in her society:
We took the value of the house from the time the man entered it until the time when he was compelled to leave due to his job having been changed. We did deem that the money and the labour which he had put into that shell, if you like, to improve it quite rightly should be his profit. We felt that it was his own personal effort, and not that of the association or the group.
Here of course the house was actually sold, but the principle can be adapted to a situation where the tenant is rewarded but the tenancy reverts to the society.However, the other profit which was made over and above that second valuation was divided between that man and his housing association. We felt, again, that part of that extra money was due to the man for his goodwill (the goodwill which he put into the association by being a good member), and he was entitled to something for his labour. We felt that some of it was due to the members for their goodwill as far as he was concerned. We came to a very happy and amicable arrangement. … We have never had a squabble. We have never had an argument over the settlement at all.[28]
Firstly it should be spread in those ad hoc tenants’ committees which spring up when the councils announce rent rises. Their immediate aim may be to resist this or that item of council policy, but what is their ultimate aim? Surely a tenant take-over is the only logical one. Then it should be spread through tenants’ and community associations, to persuade the members that the experience they have gained of community organisation could really flourish and grow in community control. Then it should be spread through the co-operative movement. Millions of council tenants are co-op members, millions of co-op members are council tenants. They need to be convinced that co-operative ownership and control of housing is really much more important than a derisory dividend on retail purchases, which is all the co-op means in most of their lives today. Then it should be spread to members of housing committees, some of whom will readily connect their own experience of the absurdities of housing policy with the advantages to be found in tenant control. Once the idea is being seriously discussed, the ordinary media of communications will spread it, criticise it, appraise it. The first thing is to get it on the agenda of all these bodies.
Then we need study of the financial and legal problems. If there were a genuine and militant upsurge of demand from below, these would rapidly follow to event, but it would be helpful to find out where the difficulties lie, and how they might be resolved, from the experience of bodies like the Co-ownership Development Society and the National Federation of Housing Societies and of the handful of existing housing co-operatives.
Finally we need a working example, a pilot project, to prove to others that it is possible. It may not be in present circumstances a universal solution, it may not be applicable everywhere. But Britain has a higher proportion of municipally owned dwellings than any other Western country. Surely there is room somewhere for an experiment in responsible citizenship, which is what is implied in the transfer of housing from municipal government to self-government.- ↑ 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 Lewis E. Waddilove: Housing Associations (P.E.P. Report, 1962).
- ↑ P. G. Gray: The British Household (The Social Survey, 1949).
- ↑ Ministry of Housing and Local Government. Parliamentary written answer, November 11, 1965.
- ↑ 4.0 4.1 4.2 Robert Millar: The New Classes: The New Patterns of British Life (Longmans, 1966).
- ↑ 5.0 5.1 5.2 Sir Milner Holland (chairman): Report of the Committee on Housing in Greater London (HMSO, 1965).
- ↑ Housing Corporation: Annual Report, 1966.
- ↑ The Guardian, October 21, 1966.
- ↑ The Labour Party: Homes of the Future, 1956.
- ↑ 9.0 9.1 Housing: A Co-operative Approach (Co-operative Union, 1959).
- ↑ 10.0 10.1 Social Ownership and Control (Co-operative Union, 1961).
- ↑ Harold Campbell: Housing Co-ops and Local Authorities (Co-operative Union, October 1961).
- ↑ Sir Parker Morris (chairman): Homes for Today and Tomorrow (Ministry of Housing and Local Government, HMSO, 1961).
- ↑ 13.0 13.1 Councils and Their Houses: Management of Estates, Eighth Report of the Housing Management Sub-Committee of the Central Housing Advisory Committee (HMSO, 1959).
- ↑ D. V. Donnison: “Housing Policy—What of the Future”, Housing, Vol. 23, No. 3, December 1961.
- ↑ J. B. Cullingworth: English Housing Trends (G. Bell & Sons, 1965).
- ↑ 16.0 16.1 Ferdynand Zweig: The Worker in an Affluent Society (Heinemann, 1961).
- ↑ 17.0 17.1 James Tucker: Honourable Estates (Gollancz, 1966).
- ↑ Stanley Alderson: Britain in the Sixties: Housing (Peguin Books, 1962).
- ↑ Ronald Frankenberg: Communities in Britain: Social Life in Town and Country (Penguin Books, 1966).
- ↑ Norman Dennis: “Changes in Function and Leadership Renewal” Sociological Review n.s.6, 1958, cited by Morris and Mogey: The Sociology of Housing (Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1965).
- ↑ 21.0 21.1 John Hayes: “Tenants’ Associations”, Society of Housing Managers Quarterly Journal, Vol. V, No. 11, July 1963.
- ↑ Gerry Williams: “Teen Canteen: End or Beginning” (anarchy 30, Vol. 3, No. 8, August 1963).
- ↑ 23.0 23.1 R. N. Morris and John Mogey: The Sociology of Housing (Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1965).
- ↑ Eric Lyons: “Domestic Building and Speculative Development”. Paper read at the RIBA on March 25, 1958 (RIBA Journal, May 1958).
- ↑ John Barr: “What Kind of Homes do People Want?” (New Society, No. 163, November 11, 1965).
- ↑ J. B. Cullingworth: Housing and Local Government in England and Wales (Allen and Unwin, 1966).
- ↑ Metropolitan Boroughs’ (Organisation and Methods) Committee: General Review of Housing Management, 1963.
- ↑ Report of 25th Annual General Meeting of NFHS. Quarterly Bulletin No. 100 July 1962.